Here is:
The Business of Business
An old debate about what companies are for has
been revived
In
2000 two American law professors, Henry Hansmann of Yale University and Reinier
Kraakman of Harvard, pronounced that the most hotly-contested debate in
corporate law had been resolved. For decades conservatives and progressives had
argued over whether the purpose of a company is to maximise shareholder value
or pursue broader social ends. Now, the conservatives had won. Anglo-Saxon
capitalism was sweeping all before it. And the world’s legal systems were
converging on the shareholder-value model. The duo could hardly have been more
unlucky in their timing. Not long after their article was published, several
companies that proudly practised shareholder-value maximisation went up in
flames: Enron, Arthur Andersen and WorldCom, among others. Six years later the
collapse of Lehman Brothers triggered a global crisis. Jack Welch, GE’s former
boss and a poster boy of the conservative school, said pursuing shareholder
value as a strategy was “the dumbest idea ever”.
Defenders
of the model might retort that a few bad apples don’t spoil the bunch. These
have now been dealt with and the laws strengthened. But the shareholder-value
model has conceptual as well as practical problems. Its proponents argue that
companies are owned by shareholders, when in fact they are “legal persons” that
own themselves.
Shareholders
just own shares — that
is, bundles of entitlements such as the right to receive dividends and to vote
on certain issues. Corporate personhood gives shareholders the benefit of
limited liability: creditors can only enforce their claims against the firm’s
assets rather than against the shareholder’s assets. It also gives companies
the benefit of capital “lock-in”, so they can pursue long-term projects: if
shareholders want their money back they have to sell their shares.
Shareholder-value
arguments are often used to press a company to do something that would create a
short-term profit for shareholders, such as accepting a takeover bid. However,
in America most legal jurisdictions have some version of the “business judgment
rule” which gives directors discretion to act in the long-term interests of the
company even if this means sacrificing short-term gains. In practice, of
course, shareholders are often not a homogeneous block with a collective
interest: traders who buy on the whiff of a bid may have a different
perspective from investors who have held the shares for decades.
With
conservatives on the defensive, progressives are now pressing their advantage.
In “How Good We Can Be”, Will Hutton, a British newspaper columnist, calls for
a “Companies Act for the 21st century”: firms should be required to declare on
incorporation their intention “to deliver particular goods and services that
serve a societal or economic need”. In a recent lecture to the British Academy,
Colin Mayer, a management professor at Oxford University, called for companies
to be required to “articulate their purposes”. Directors should be held to
account for the delivery of these stated purposes. Controlling ownership should
be in the hands of people who can ensure that directors discharge their
responsibilities. Mr Mayer says a striking number of what he sees as the
world’s best firms, such as Bosch, Carlsberg, Bertelsmann and
Tata,
are owned by foundations that are pledged to pursue the public good. Darrell
West of the Brookings Institution in Washington, DC, notes the decline of the
idea that companies are creatures of the state, given the privilege of
incorporation in return for pursuing a broad public purpose.
This
all sounds very enlightened. But who will decide whether new companies are
likely to serve the public good? Will a committee of the great and the good
interrogate young app designers about the social benefits of their inventions?
Will foreign competitors who are not required to pass a public-interest test be
barred from the market? Or domestic entrepreneurs who choose to incorporate
abroad?
Nor
are foundations the paragons that Sir Colin imagines: they are frequently
created to reduce corporate tax burdens and invariably hand power to a select
group of insiders. Carlsberg is struggling, after going heavily into the
Russian market, and recently replaced its CEO. Bertelsmann remains highly
dependent on its German television stations despite repeated attempts to join
the digital revolution. Tata has lots of underperforming businesses as well as
some excellent ones. As for Mr West and the supposed virtues of companies as
creatures of the state, the one-word response to that is: Petrobras.…is
business
The
secret of the modern company’s success is precisely that it is such an
open-ended organisation. Until the 19th century companies had to pursue a
public purpose (imperial domination, usually) in return for limited liability.
But various governments, starting in Britain and America, swept away these
restrictions and let companies form for no other purpose than to engage in
business. This simple act of liberalisation did as much as anything to create
the modern economy. Open-endedness lets companies evolve: startups have very
different purposes to mature businesses.
Open-endedness
reflects the realities of corporate life: far from being slaves to the share
price, as progressives imagine, most companies are engaged in a constant
process of negotiation between managers and investors over their strategy and
time horizons.
Mature
companies such as Shell, Intel and Nestlé often invest for the long term
without a squeak from fund managers. New-economy companies such as Google,
Facebook and, particularly, Amazon have had no difficulty in persuading
investors to sacrifice short-term returns (and indeed any control whatsoever) in
return for long-term rewards.
That
businesses do not have to declare a lofty purpose so as to enjoy the privilege
of incorporation is not a bug but a feature. Indeed, it is the defining feature
of the modern corporation. Change it and you wreck the entire machine.
This
article first appeared in The Economist’s Schumpeter column on March 19th 2015.
No comments:
Post a Comment